top of page

Ports regulation in South Africa: An equitable tax rate approach




Copyright © 2023 Inclusive Society Institute PO Box 12609

Mill Street

Cape Town, 8000 South Africa 235-515 NPO All rights reserved. No part of this publication may be reproduced or transmitted in any form or by any means without the permission in writing from the Inclusive Society Institute D I S C L A I M E R

Views expressed in this report do not necessarily represent the views of

the Inclusive Society Institute or those of their respective Board or Council

members.


JANUARY 2023


Ports regulation in South Africa: An equitable tax rate approach

by Mahesh Fakir, Ex-CEO of Ports Regulator of South Africa & Prof Mihalis Chasomeris (Corresponding Author), Associate Professor, Graduate School of Business and Leadership, University of KwaZulu-Natal


Abstract


Background: The Ports Regulator of South Africa (PRSA) allows South Africa’s National Ports Authority (NPA) to use a rate of return pricing methodology called the Required Revenue (RR) model to annually apply for tariff increases. From 2011 to 2017, the PRSA allowed the use of the pass-through of corporate tax rate (28%) approach in the RR model. However, from 2018 it applied an equitable tax rate approach that is derived from the corporate tax rate applied to the group profit, shared between the sums of all the pre-tax profits of profit-making divisions within the group. It can be argued that the equitable tax rate approach should have been used from 2011.


Objectives: This paper compares the pass-through of corporate tax rate approach to the use of an equitable tax rate in the RR model from 2011 to 2017.


Method: The calculation of the equitable tax rate uses Transnet’s annual segmental financial statements. The results are compared with the revenue results from the pass-through of the corporate tax rate approach.


Results: Applying the equitable tax rate (15.73%) as opposed to a pass-through tax rate (28%), the NPA revenue would have been R2.6 billion (US$187m) lower, a substantial saving for port users.


Conclusion: Continuing to apply this equitable tax rate approach could result in future annual savings of about R500m (US$36m) for port users if the NPA remains a division. However, if the NPA is incorporated as a subsidiary, then the original pass-through of corporate tax rate approach should resume.


Keywords: Port Pricing, Rate of return regulation, Ports Regulator of South Africa, National Ports Authority, Transnet. JEL: R48,

This article was first published in the Journal of Economic and Financial Sciences, Vol 15, No1 (2022) Fakir, M. & Chasomeris, M.G., 2022, ‘Ports regulation in South Africa: An equitable tax rate approach’, Journal of Economic and Financial Sciences 15(1), a736. https://doi.org/10.4102/jef.v15i1.736 Copyright: © 2022. The Author(s). Licensee: AOSIS.


Introduction


There is economic regulation of ports in several countries including South Africa, Australia, India, Greece, Peru, Philippines, Portugal, Canada, the Netherlands and Brazil (Angelopoulos et al., 2019). The regulation of port prices (tariffs) typically uses either a price cap methodology or a rate of return methodology (Gumede and Chasomeris, 2017). In South Africa, a version of the rate of return methodology forms the basis of what the Ports Regulator of South Africa (PRSA) refers to as the Required Revenue (RR) model (Ports Regulator of South Africa, 2017a). An RR model calculation is used to determine the total quantum of revenue that the National Port Authority (NPA) may collect in any one year from port users after approved adjustments to port tariffs by the Ports Regulator. The RR model incorporates port user payments for infrastructure, operating expenses, and enables the Ports Authority, (as the regulated entity) to make a risk-adjusted return on port assets (as determined by a weighted average cost of capital (WACC) formula) (Gumede and Chasomeris, 2018).


Several of the values of the variables used in the calculation of the RR model have been critiqued by port users and other port stakeholders. For example, evidence shows a substantial overvaluation of the NPA regulatory asset base and an unrealistically high asset beta that assumed the NPA to be a higher risk entity than it actually is under regulation. Such issues have resulted in higher prices to port users and higher revenues and profits to the NPA (Chasomeris, 2015; Meyiwa and Chasomeris, 2020). This paper continues the constructive critique of the RR model and focuses on the treatment of tax in the RR model (a form of rate of return regulation). This paper compares the pass-through of corporate tax approach to the use of the equitable tax rate in the RR model. It refines the rate of return methodology and indeed the RR model, by considering the case where a regulated entity is not a ‘stand-alone’ entity, but a ‘division’ within a ‘group’ consisting of many ‘divisions’ not individually liable for the payment of taxes. An Equitable Tax Rate takes the losses of the loss-making divisions that are part of the group into account, and further, the principle of proportionality is applied between the profitable divisions in apportioning and sharing the tax burden to the size of their profits.


South Africa’s National Ports Act of 2005 (Act) envisages a commercial ports system whose state ownership of port infrastructure is vested in the National Ports Authority (NPA) as a state monopoly, and further creates the Ports Regulator of South Africa as an independent economic regulator to ensure fairness in pricing (RSA, 2005) and prevent monopolistic abuse. The Act sets out that the NPA be incorporated as a subsidiary wholly owned by the Transnet group (SOC), upon the Act coming into effect. Up to the present, over a decade and a half since the passing of the Act, the NPA has remained a division of Transnet rather than the ‘subsidiary’ envisaged, for reasons beyond the scope of this paper. In the application of its RR tariff methodology, the Ports Regulator had previously treated the NPA as a subsidiary in the calculation of allowed revenue for tax, as incorporation could have happened at any time. In 2017 the Regulator for its 2018/19 tariff determination modified its tax calculation to reflect a reduced tax allowance in treating the NPA as a division.


This paper contributes in several ways. First, in attempting to contribute to the work of other Economic Regulators regulating unincorporated divisions of a corporate group, it examines theoretical differences in the tax treatment of regulated subsidiaries or stand-alone regulated entities, as opposed to regulated divisions within a corporate group. It then derives formulae for the new Equitable Tax Rate approach used by the Ports Regulator to assist in correcting such ‘disproportionalities’ arising out of the corporate form of regulated entities. Second, it reports on the development of a model for a new “equitable tax rate” method, which considers the profits and losses of other divisions with a group, for the determination of a fair tax rate for a regulated division within a group. Third, it uses NPA financial statements for the period 2011 to 2017, to provide an empirical application and analyses of the equitable tax rate approach in the calculation of the RR model. The relevant formulae and a practical system of implementing the “equitable tax rate” approach, ensures that the profits and losses of other divisions with a group, is taken into account in determining regulatory tax allowances for a regulated division within an unregulated group using the Required Revenue (rate of return) Tariff Methodology. Finally, it explores and confirms the Ports Regulator of South Africa’s (2017) approach to taxation of the NPA and further, extrapolates this to the calculation of the tariff determinations in previous years in order to estimate future port user savings through reduced port tariffs, as well as the potential loss to port users over the seven years of regulation (2011 to 2017), before the new equitable tax rate approach was conceived and applied.


Literature Review


South Africa’s system of nine state-owned commercial ports is rare internationally, and the economic price regulation of this system is largely unprecedented. There is one National Ports Authority (NPA) (as opposed to regional or municipal ports authorities). Planning of investment in port infrastructure and marine services is done nationally. Hence, there may be cross-subsidization between ports and port users and a sharing of resources between the nine ports. The NPA also controls the licensing of terminal operators and this has been an issue with some stakeholders that believe there are competition issues and a conflict of interest as the NPA, under Transnet, issues licenses to both private sector terminals and their sister division called Transnet Port Terminals (Meyiwa and Chasomeris, 2020). Consequently, the NPA makes a single annual tariff submission to the Ports Regulator, using the RR model to calculate the required revenue for the entire NPA. This is in contrast to the regulation of ports in other countries like India and Australia. In India, the Tariff Authority for Major Ports (TEMP) regulates the 12 major ports and a separate tariff application submission is made for each port. Thus, the income and expenditure of each port is known by the TEMP. A lack of published audited financial information by ports has hindered public participation in the regulation of South Africa’s ports. Furthermore, as the NPA is a regulated division of an unregulated Transnet Group, together with consolidated accounting techniques, creates further complexities and inadequate access to information that could improve regulation of the port authority. Indeed, a study by Meyiwa and Chasomeris (2020) used content analyses to examine 137 port stakeholders’ submissions from 2009/2010 to 2018/2019. They concluded that the governance structure of the NPA was shown to promote anticompetitive behaviour and they recommend a swift incorporation of the NPA as a stand-alone entity outside of Transnet.


Acciaro (2013: 211) reviewed port pricing literature from 1974 to 2013 and found that most studies make use of anecdotal evidence and that “from a methodological point of view, there are very few empirical studies and… most papers that deal with port pricing as a core issue make use of conceptual economic models and game theory.” The regulation of port prices (tariffs) typically uses either a price cap methodology or a rate of return methodology (Gumede and Chasomeris, 2017).


South Africa’s National Ports Act of 2005 (RSA, 2005: S30) sets out a commercial ports system of nine ports whose infrastructure is owned by the state through a National Ports Authority as a state-owned monopoly (a part of the Transnet state owned logistics group), and therefore creates the Ports Regulator whose functions in terms of section 30(1) of the Act are to:


  • “Exercise economic regulation of the ports system in line with government’s strategic objectives;

  • Promote equity of access to ports and to facilities and services provided in ports;

  • Monitor the activities of the Authority to ensure that it performs its functions in accordance with this act.”


The Ports Regulator in its economic regulation function, has adopted the RR approach that transparently builds up cost and other components. The Regulator (Ports Regulator of South Africa, 2017a:5,6) explains that the RR approach is used to determine fair port pricing for all port stakeholders. It allows cost recovery as well as a reasonable profit (return on assets) to the regulated entity, and therefore allows for all the regulated entity’s operating costs, depreciation, and notably for the purposes of this paper, the profit tax that the entity requires to pay on allowed profit. The method protects port users from “paying excessive monopolistic prices, with the argument being that monopolistic firms should be required to charge the price that would prevail in a competitive market”.


This RR approach, in addition, fulfills the requirements of the National Ports Act directives which require that the Regulator ensures that approved tariff levels allow the Ports Authority to (Ports Regulator of South Africa, 2017a: 5):


  • “Recover its investment in owning, controlling and administering ports and its investment in port services and facilities;

  • Recover its costs in maintaining, operating, controlling and administering ports and its costs in providing port services and facilities; and

  • Make a profit commensurate with the risk involved in ports services and facilities”.


Indeed, there appears to be consensus in the literature on the importance of cost recovery for port infrastructure (Haralambides, 2002; Santos et al, 2016). In the case of the NPA, in addition to full cost recovery, a return on port assets related to risk is allowed, and is calculated using the RR approach. The formula for the RR, as per the Port Tariff Methodology of the Ports Regulator for Tariff Years 2018/19 – 2020/21 (Ports Regulator of South Africa, 2017a:7), is as follows:

“Where: RR = Revenue Required; v = Value of the assets used in the regulated services; d = Accumulated depreciation on such assets; w = Working Capital; r = Regulated Return on Capital; D = Depreciation accounted for in the period of the tariff; E = Operating costs (OPEX); T = Taxation expense; C = Claw-back; ETIMC = Excessive Tariff Increase Margin Credit; WEGO = Weighted Efficiency Gains from Operations; (v – d + w) = Regulated Asset Base”.


This formula is an international standard building block model. Tariffs for the year ahead, and two following years of the multi-year methodology validity period, are based on forecasts of the variables of the RR formula listed above. As each year passes, the forecasted assumptions are replaced with actual data, and when all the actual data is available for a tariff year, the formula is used to re-determine the tariff, and a corrective adjustment is made in the following year via the claw-back mechanism (C) (Ports Regulator of South Africa, 2017a). Quantities pertaining to the various variables are either clawed back or given back from or to the regulated entity’s RR, to address any differences between estimates and actuals. Claw-back calculations are performed each year within a multi-year tariff determination system. As actual data for the first tariff year will only be available in the second year, the applicable claw-back, will only be completely implemented in the third year, often on a 50/50 basis. As an example, cargo volumes for any year’s tariff calculation can only be an estimate, until the year has passed, whereupon the actual measured volumes will be used for the calculation of claw-backs. Similarly, any component or variable of the RR formula may thus be estimated as accurately as possible in a particular year, and subsequently rectified using the claw-back mechanism in the subsequent two years when the actual data is known.


The items in the formula dealing with “Excessive Tariff Increase Margin Credit (ETIMC)” as well as with “Weighted Efficiency Gains from Operations (WEGO)” (Ports Regulator of South Africa, 2017a:7) are notable modifications by the Ports Regulator to the standard building blocks of the RR approach, and while ETIMC has been used previously by the Ports Regulator as an innovative ‘savings’ mechanism in the regulatory practice in previous years to reduce potential higher than inflation tariff spikes, the WEGO is a new innovation that incentivizes performance improvements in the operation of the ports system by the use of either additional or reduced profits (Ports Regulator of South Africa, 2017a).


To correct for differences in estimates, versus what actually materializes in the year in which the tariffs are applied, the RR approach also contains the ETIMC. As explained in the published Methodology: “the ETIMC mechanism allows for large increases in required revenue and/or tariffs that may arise from volume volatility or substantial capital expenditure programmes in future years to be partly offset by moderately higher tariff increases in the short-term” (Ports Regulator of South Africa, 2017a: 7). Thus, amounts that could be clawed-back, reducing tariffs in the following year, could also rather be retained in the ETIMC facility to be used in reducing tariffs in years in which higher prices are anticipated, thus resulting in a smoother price path and greater certainty in pricing.


Several concerns about the RR model have been raised including that it may “incentivise unnecessary port capital expenditure (investments)”, “bloat operating expenditure” and set port authority prices at higher “levels that are not in the best interests of the country’s trade competitiveness and economic development objectives” (Chasomeris, 2015; Gumede and Chasomeris, 2017). In addition, port stakeholders (mainly port users) have complained that the application of the RR model has allowed the NPA to generate excessive profits that are not adequately reinvested into the port infrastructure and marine services, but are rather used to subsidise other less profitable divisions in the Transnet Group (Meyiwa and Chasomeris, 2020).


Treatment of Taxation within the Revenue Required Approach


In terms of South Africa’s Income Tax Act of 1962 (RSA, 1962) (as amended), a “(Pty) Ltd”, as a subsidiary of a holding company pays tax directly to the revenue authorities at the corporate tax rate (presently 28%), whilst the tax liability of a group consisting of divisions is by the group alone. From the inception of the Ports Regulator’s interim methodology in the 2014/15 financial year (Ports Regulator of South Africa, 2013a) and also in the first multi-year methodology for 2015/16 to 2017/18 (Ports Regulator of South Africa, 2014a), taxation has been a pass-through expense set at the corporate tax rate of 28%. In Equation 2 below, “Net revenue before tax allowance is the revenue after all costs, including interest and depreciation, have been accounted for, ie. it is the net return to equity before being grossed up to make allowances for taxation” (Ports Regulator of South Africa, 2013a).

The reasons for the 28% pass-through tax rate approach may include simplicity, ease of calculation and certainty to the sustainability of the NPA. In addition, according to the National Ports Act 12 of 2005, the NPA was expected to be incorporated as a wholly–owned subsidiary of the Transnet Group, rather than remain a division, and it was therefore correct for the Regulator to contemplate that this could have happened at any time. Thus, in terms of the Act, it was not inappropriate for the Regulator to assume the incorporation of the NPA into National Ports Authority (Pty) Ltd with Transnet as the sole member and shareholder, as before actual incorporation or registration, the Act deems it to be the Authority and expects it to function as the Authority.


The Ports Regulator’s methodology uses a ‘vanilla weighted average cost of capital (WACC)’ to calculate a return on equity, which comprises a “post-tax cost of equity” and a “pre-tax cost of debt” (Ports Regulator of South Africa, 2013a). However, the idea that this is a pragmatic solution of a ‘notional’ tax allowance as an approximation to the actual tax payable by the Ports Authority, in practice comes nowhere close to satisfactory, as the incorporation of the Authority (from a division into a subsidiary) had not materialized more than a decade after the Act had been promulgated, and the warning issued by the NPA (TNPA, 2012:25,26) “[the] Authority is not a legal entity for which tax is calculated and paid. Furthermore, any attempt to estimate a pro rata share of actual tax paid by Transnet may be quite unrepresentative of the tax burden that would have be borne by the Authority had it been a separate corporation.” seemed to be without merit. Indeed, this article will show (see table 5) that over the seven years of regulation (2011 to 2017), tax allowances provided for by the Ports Regulator within its RR tariff methodology have been disproportionately large in relation to the actual tax liability of the Transnet Group in most years. In four of the seven years, the NPA tax allowance was over half (50%) of the actual tax liability of the Transnet Group, and much more than the group tax in FY2016, at 216,30%. A solution that did try to estimate a pro rata share of the actual tax liability of the Transnet group therefore had to be found.


In its second Multi-Year Tariff Methodology for 2018/19 to 2020/21 (Ports Regulator of South Africa, 2017a), the Ports Regulator states that it will accept the current corporate tax rate of 28% (t) adjusted in relation to the taxation of the Transnet Group as a whole, as the NPA is a division within the group. It envisaged a proportional tax rate, with assumption that the NPA is an operating division that does not independently pay tax, as opposed to a subsidiary of Transnet Group which would have been liable for its own tax submission. This annually approximated proportional tax rate will be readjusted through the claw back mechanism from information it would obtain from annually published audited Transnet Group Financial Statements. This represented a departure from previous methodologies in intent, and the actual mechanism of how it could work. Indeed, the Ports Regulator of South Africa (2017b: 12,13) concludes that “the continued revenue allowance of 28% of profit for NPA taxes can only be fair for a stand-alone entity paying its taxes directly to the South African Revenue Service (SARS) and that if the NPA remains one of the profit-making divisions of Transnet, among other such divisions, an equitable tax rate for the fair sharing of the group tax payable in any year has to be calculated for all profit-making divisions or business units.” Section 3 explains how to derive and calculate an equitable tax rate.


Research Methodology: An Equitable (Proportional) Tax Rate


In a group scenario, the profits of profit-making divisions are reduced by the losses of loss-making divisions before tax payable is calculated. Put in another way, if the revenue of each division is equal, then the higher costs of the loss-making divisions add to the lower costs of the profitable divisions, thus reducing the overall taxable profit payable by the group. In general terms the following equations can describe the scenarios with respect to corporate structure and corporate tax liability in any applicable year.


Total tax liability in a year for a group of n number of divisions each numbered i =1 to n:

Where: t = the corporate tax rate; = Pre-tax Profit of profitable division i; = Loss of loss-making division I; Td = total tax liability of group of divisions


On the other hand, total tax liability in a year for the same divisions above treated as separate companies, noting that loss making companies pay zero tax is given by:

Where: t = the corporate tax rate; = Pre-tax Profit of profitable company i; Ts = total tax liability of group of divisions treated as separate companies.

Where: t = the corporate tax rate; = Pre-tax Profit of profitable company/division i; = Loss of loss-making company/division i; Ts = total tax liability of group of divisions treated as separate companies; Td = total tax liability of group of divisions.


Thus, in any tax year, the aggregation of divisions incorporated as separate companies is liable to pay more tax than the corporate group consisting of unincorporated divisions by an amount equal to the sum of losses of the loss-making divisions, which illustrates how the losses of loss-making divisions within a group offset or dilutes the profits of profit-making divisions in reducing the tax liability of the group, leaving the group with comparatively more available cash.


If one or more of the divisions in the group are regulated entities, with tax being calculated separately as part of an RR regulatory approach, and tax is calculated on the basis of a pass-through at the corporate tax rate (t) then this could result in:


  • disproportionately larger tax contribution by regulated divisions towards group tax than unregulated divisions;

  • the group obtaining much more cash from the regulated divisions than is fair for the payment of tax by the group;

  • unfairness to the users of the services of the regulated divisions as they would be required to pay higher prices to make up higher required revenue than proportionally necessary for their contribution to group tax.


One way for regulators to determine a fair approach to the calculation of taxes, for regulated divisions within a group, within the RR methodology is to determine an equitable tax rate. The formula of an equitable tax rate (te) which, when applied to all profitable divisions treated as separate companies, must result in the tax applicable when the corporate tax rate (t) is applied to the aggregate profits of the group of divisions. In mathematical terms:

Therefore, to determine te as outlined in the problem statement above:

but the term ( ) is equivalent to the aggregate taxable profit of the group (which accounts for divisional losses) which can be written as Pg


Thus, from the equations above, it is clear why the Regulator Record of Decision (Ports Regulator of South Africa, 2017b:13) concludes that the equitable tax rate (te) applicable to any of the profit-making divisions in a financial year will thus be the corporate tax rate multiplied by the (Transnet net profit and divided by the sum of profits of profitable divisions or segments):

Where: te = equitable tax rate, t = the corporate tax rate, Pg = Transnet Group total pre-tax profit for the financial year, Σ𝑃𝑖 = The Sum of pre-tax profits of profitable divisions or segments for the financial year.


The method for the determination of an equitable tax rate requires two other sets of data, namely the group profit on a year on year basis, as well as group segmental data which shows either the revenues and costs associated with each division or business unit (segmental income statement), or pre-tax profit and loss data per division in the year. In this case it is the Transnet Group, within which the NPA is a division. In addition, it would be useful for such data to have been published over a number of years in order to determine a reasonable moving average of an equitable rate that can be applied in any one year and readjusted using the ‘claw-back’ variable within the RR formula used by regulators.


The equitable tax rate formula in future would thus be applied as follows (Ports Regulator of South Africa, 2017b): it would be applied for the NPA as a profit-making division; it would use the claw-back mechanism to readjust the estimated equitable tax rate when audited segmental financials become available; it would be used in the calculation of cost of equity (resulting in a higher return); it would use a five year moving average of previously calculated ‘actual’ equitable tax rate and then utilize the claw-back to readjust for the actual equitable tax rate for the applicable year. The application of the equitable tax rate calculation would be on condition that the Transnet Group annually publish segmental financials that have been audited, for the group and each division, otherwise the regulator will not provide for tax in the RR, and the RR tax allowance would be considered to be already allowed within the profit allowed (Ports Regulator of South Africa, 2017b).


Results and discussion: Application of the equitable tax rate in the regulation of South Africa’s ports


This section applies the equitable tax rate approach to segmental financial data that was collected from published Transnet Annual Reports from 2011 to 2017. The Transnet divisional profits and losses relative to the Group profits are recorded in Table 1 for five divisions, namely the National Ports Authority (NPA), Transnet Port Terminals (TPT), Transnet Freight Rail (TFR), Transnet Pipelines (TPL) and Transnet Engineering (TRE). All other business units including head office are recorded as all other segments. The total taxable group profit is the arithmetic sum of each of the divisional profits including all other segments and elimination of intersegmental transactions.


Table 1: Transnet Divisional Profits and Losses as a Percentage of Group Profits

Source: Authors compiled and calculated from: Transnet Annual Financial Statements: segmental reports (Transnet 2012; 2013; 2014; 2015; 2016; 2017; 2018).

Table 1 shows losses of loss-making divisions listed in italics whilst those of profit-making divisions are listed in bold. The NPA contribution to group profits has been both consistent and high over the period that it has been regulated. TFR has on many occasions exceeded the NPA profits but has also shown some years of poor profitability as well as losses. TPL as a regulated division has also shown consistent profitability, with Transnet Engineering showing profits in some years and losses in others. In particular, in examining the 2016 financial year, it is clear that the NPA recorded a profit close to thrice that of the group as a whole, due to the lowest aggregate divisional profit and the largest aggregate divisional loss incurred by the group over the seven-year period under consideration. In this regard it is not impossible to conceive that the taxation allowed by the Ports Regulator covered the tax liability of the group as a whole and even contributed to profits of the group, and that this may legitimately be regarded as an unfair burden on port stakeholders who cover this required revenue through user charges for the use of port infrastructure owned by the NPA as well as for related marine services performed by the NPA. Taxation allowed for in the RR of the NPA amounted to R889 million, for financial year ending 2016, whilst the profit tax payable on the R1468 million group profit was only R411 million. This implies that a division within a group benefited from a tax allowance that was 216% of what its group was actually liable to pay to the tax authorities for that financial year.


Table 2 aggregates the sum of all profitable segments as well as all loss-making segments in the Transnet Group for the financial years under consideration and calculates the equitable tax rate for each financial year. As expected, the equitable tax rate in each year is significantly lower than the 28% corporate tax rate on profits. The average equitable tax rate over the seven-year period was calculated at 15.73%.


Table 2: Calculation of Equitable Tax Rate (%) from Divisional Profit and Loss (R’million) data

Source: Authors compiled and calculated from Transnet Annual Financial Statements: segmental reports (Transnet 2012; 2013; 2014; 2015; 2016; 2017; 2018).

In any year, regulators are obliged to provide a tariff, before segmental results on profits are known, and the tariff contains within it, the revenue required for the tax liability for the regulated entity as per the RR regulatory methodology. When the corporate tax rate was taken for granted as the correct rate, 28% was always used. Now that it is realized that this results in unwarranted revenue, an approximate tax rate has to be used, then corrected in the following year through the claw-back mechanism allowed for within the RR calculations. It makes sense that instead of using the maximum of the corporate tax rate and then clawing back on this after actual segmental results are published, the average equitable tax rate over several years should be used as a closer approximation of what the actual equitable rate will be when it is published. The claw-back mechanism may then be used to adjust the tax revenue either upwards or downwards as may be appropriate.


Table 3: Calculation of Tax on Group Profit at 28% compared to application of the derived Equitable Tax Rate to Profitable segments (R’million)

Source: Authors compiled and calculated from Transnet Annual Financial Statements: segmental reports (Transnet 2012; 2013; 2014; 2015; 2016; 2017; 2018).

Table 3 demonstrates that the application of the equitable tax rate in each year, to the aggregate of the profitable segments in the group, yielded the exact profit tax on the group profit at the 28% corporate tax rate. Figures in the last column calculated by applying the equitable tax rate to the sum of profitable segments/divisions (te x ΣPi) exactly equals figures in the third column calculated from applying the corporate tax rate to the group profit (t x Pg). This is theoretically demonstrated below as follows:


If:



It means:



which implies that:



Where: te = equitable tax rate; t = the corporate tax rate; Pg = Transnet Group pre-tax profit; Σ𝑃𝑖 = The Sum of profits of profitable divisions; P1, P2, P3, … ,Pn = Individual profits of each profitable segment numbered 1 to n.


This confirms that if the equitable tax rate as derived, is applied to the profits of each profitable division separately, their tax contributions to the group will in aggregate amount to the group tax at the corporate tax rate (tPg). Thus, a much lower tax rate, the equitable tax rate, applied to the profits of the profitable divisions in each financial year, is sufficient to fund the full annual tax liability of the group albeit that the group pays tax at the higher corporate tax rate of 28%. Thus, a regulator may exercise this equitable tax rate approach for the calculation of an equitable tax share for the particular regulated division within a group, regardless of the non-regulated divisions, as long as their audited segmental pre-tax profit and loss information is made available.


More importantly for regulation, is that a regulator of a divisional entity may apply a lower tax rate in calculating the tax allowance for the required revenue of the regulated entity, thus saving the users of the services of the regulated entity money, as long as the lower tax rate that is applied, equates to the equitable tax rate as derived. This is because it is only at the equitable tax rate, that the tax allowed for the regulated division will comprise the minimum fair share of that division (as one amongst all profitable divisions) towards the tax liability of the group as a whole, at the corporate tax rate.


Only when there are no loss-making segments/divisions within the group, will the sum of profits of profitable divisions equal the group profit, and only then will the equitable tax rate reach its maximum value, equaling the corporate tax rate. That is, in the equation te ΣPi = tPg , if ΣPi = Pg, then it follows that under this condition te = t. For as long as there are loss making segments/divisions, the group profit will be smaller than the aggregate of profits of profitable divisions, and the equitable tax rate will be lower than the corporate tax rate.


Table 4 shows a comparison of tax allowed by the Ports Regulator versus tax allowance calculated using the equitable tax rate formula for each financial year from 2011 to 2017. The equitable tax rate result in each year is significantly lower than the tax previously allowed thus indicating that the use of this method could result in substantial savings to port users. Specifically, a saving of between a low of 27.97% in 2011 to a high of 77.58% in 2016 If the method had been used from the outset, then the average percentage reduction in tax revenues for the seven-year period would have been 43.83%. In quantitative terms this would have amounted to an aggregate saving for port users of just over R2.6 billion (US$187m) over the seven-year period.


Table 4: Calculation of tax savings to port users if the derived Equitable Tax Rate to Profitable segments method was applied instead of the corporate tax rate of 28% (R’million)

Source: Authors compiled and calculated from Ports Regulator Records of Decision (Ports Regulator of South Africa, 2011; 2012; 2013b; 2014b; 2015; 2016a; 2016b).


While future savings to port users depends on the profitability of each of the divisions and the overall profits of the Transnet group going forward, as these are the determinants of the equitable tax rate approach, possible savings to port users in 2016 and 2017 years are over R500 million per year ($36m). It is therefore not inconceivable that the use of the equitable tax rate approach could save port users similar significant amounts in future.


Table 5: Addressing the disproportionality: Previous Allowed tax vs Equitable tax rate as % Group tax

Source: Authors compiled and calculated from: Transnet Annual Financial Statements: segmental reports (Transnet 2012; 2013; 2014; 2015; 2016; 2017; 2018); Ports Regulator Records of Decision (Ports Regulator of South Africa, 2011; 2012; 2013b; 2014b; 2015; 2016a; 2016b).


Table 5 shows that the equitable tax rate is consistently below 50% of the Group tax liability in all financial years, even in 2016 when the largest division in the Transnet Group, TFR made a loss. This makes much more sense as the NPA is only one of five of the usual profit-making divisions, albeit that its profit has been consistently large over the years of regulation. The spread between the smallest (12,7%) and largest (48,48%) tax derived from the use of the equitable tax rate (as a percentage of the group tax) has also narrowed, as compared to the previously allowed tax, which is spread between 19,58% and 216,30% respectively. This indicates greater consistency of resulting tax burden to users. Table 5 also confirms that the use of the equitable tax rate does not result in the divisional tax allowance exceeding the group tax liability in any year, indicating greater fairness and potential future savings to users.


Conclusion


The simple pass-through of corporate tax rates by regulators using rate of return regulation in the economic regulation of unincorporated divisions of an unregulated corporate group results in unfairly high prices to users and excess revenue to the group. In South Africa, it has been observed by the Ports Regulator, that a tax allowed at the corporate tax rate of 28% on the NPA profit as a part of the required revenue calculation, has been excessive when compared to what the Transnet Group was liable to pay as tax in any particular year, over the period when the “tax pass-through” approach was in effect. While an allowance of 28% of profit for the NPA would have been fair if it was a subsidiary or a ‘stand-alone’ company directly paying its taxes to the tax authorities, while it is still a division, the only fair rate that a regulator should use for the calculation of allowed revenue for taxes should be the Equitable Tax Rate.


As compared to a pass-through approach, the Equitable Tax Rate takes into account the losses of the loss-making divisions/segments/business units that are part of the group, and further, the principle of proportionality is applied between the profitable divisions in apportioning and sharing the tax burden in relation to the size of their profits. The use of the Equitable Tax Rate as opposed to a pass-through approach, also ensures that in no period is the tax allowed by the Regulator more than the tax liability of the group as a whole. The Equitable Tax Rate approach therefore addresses this anomaly which is characterised by an unfair price burden on the users of goods and services of regulated divisions, as well as unfair windfall profits for an unregulated group (the Transnet Group) from its regulated division(s) (the NPA).


The Equitable Tax Rate formulae derived for the calculation of an appropriate tax allowance in this context, used with the claw-back mechanism, forms a pragmatic system of addressing this problem, as it is simple in its conception and easily implementable without onerous data constraints. Its practical implementation shows how the NPA administered prices could be lowered. Specifically, calculations using Transnet’s annual segmental financial statements show that over the period 2011 to 2017 by applying the equitable tax rate (average of 15.73%) as opposed to a pass-through tax rate (28%), NPA revenue would have been R2.6 billion (US$187m) lower, a substantial saving for port users.


Continuing to apply this approach could result in future annual savings of about R500m per annum (US$36m) for port users if the NPA remains a division. However, if it is incorporated as a subsidiary, as required by the National Ports Act, then the original ‘pass-through’ approach of the prevailing corporate tax rate adopted previously by the Ports Regulator, in anticipation of the imminent implementation of the Act, should resume.


As this paper attempts to make a contribution on a methodological aspect and a circumstantial legal variation in the practical application of the rate of return economic regulatory methodology as adopted in a South African ports context, it will refrain from making any judgement on the repayment, or the attribution of blame, for the substantial amount of additional taxation allowed over the period concerned, in the absence of guidance on such circumstances within the body of knowledge of the rate of return methodology. This may well be within the scope of a future study.


However, to its credit, it is noted that the Ports Regulator did not just blindly apply an academic interpretation of rate of return methodology. Rather it both recognised the circumstantial issues at play, as well as derived the necessary equitable tax formula and thus modified its implementation of rate of return regulation in fairness and to the benefit of port users. It is therefore complimented on standing true to its principles in service to the ports’ community and the wider economy, and for its academic contribution to the modification and application of economic regulatory methodology.


References


Acciaro, M. (2013). A Critical Review of Port Pricing Literature: What Role for Academic Research? The Asian Journal of Shipping and Logistics, Vol.29 No.2, pp.207-228.


Angelopoulos, J., Chlomoudis, C., Flegkas, C., Leonardou, P., & Vrysagotis, V. (2019). Uncharted Waters-Independent Regulation for Port Concessions. Paper presented at the International Association of Maritime Economists Conference, June 25th–28th. Athens.


Chasomeris, M.G. (2015). Port Infrastructure Pricing: A Critique of the Revenue Required Methodology. International Journal of Transport Economics XLII (2) June 2015: 153-170.


Gumede, S. and Chasomeris, M. G. (2017). A Critique of South Africa’s National Ports Authority’s Revenue Required Pricing Methodology. International Journal of Transport Economics, 44(4).


Gumede, S., and Chasomeris, M. (2018). Pricing strategy and tariff structure for a port authority: a case study of South Africa. Maritime Policy & Management, 45:6, 756-769.


Haralambidies, H.E. (2002). Competition, Excess Capacity, and Pricing of Port Infrastructure, International Journal of Maritime Economics. Issue 4 pp.323-347. Doi: 10.1057/palgrave.ijme.9100053.


Meyiwa, A. and Chasomeris, M. (2020) South Africa’s Port Doctrine: Dilemmas and the Way Forward. Maritime Studies, 19, pp. 179-191. DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s40152-020-00166-2.


Ports Regulator of South Africa (2017a) Port Tariff Methodology For Tariff Years 2018/19 – 2020/21, available at: https://www.portsregulator.org/images/documents/Final-Tariff-Methodology-1819-2021.pdf [Accessed: 6 October 2018]


Ports Regulator of South Africa (2013a) Regulatory Manual for the Tariff Year 2014/15, available at: https://www.portsregulator.org/images/documents/Regulatory_Manual_for_the_Tariff_Year_2014_2015.pdf [Accessed: 6 October 2018]


Ports Regulator of South Africa (2014a) Regulatory Manual for the Tariff Year 2015/16 – 2017/18, available at: https://www.portsregulator.org/images/documents/Regulatory-Manual-for-the-Tariff-Years-2015_2016-2017_18.pdf [Accessed: 6 October 2018]


Ports Regulator of South Africa (2010) Record of Decision - Tariff Application by the National Ports Authority for the Tariff Year 2010/2011, available at: https://www.portsregulator.org/images/documents/Record-of-Decision-TNPA-Tariff-Application-2010-11.pdf [Accessed: 6 October 2018]


Ports Regulator of South Africa (2011) Record of Decision - Tariff Application by the National Ports Authority for the Tariff Year 2011/2012, available at: https://www.portsregulator.org/images/documents/Record-of-Decision-TNPA-Tariff-Application-2011-12.pdf [Accessed: 6 October 2018]


Ports Regulator of South Africa (2012) Record of Decision - Tariff Application by the National Ports Authority for the Tariff Year 2012/2013, available at: https://www.portsregulator.org/images/documents/Record-of-Decision-TNPA-Tariff-Application-2012-13.pdf [Accessed: 6 October 2018]


Ports Regulator of South Africa (2013b) Record of Decision - Tariff Application by the National Ports Authority for the Tariff Year 2013/2014, available at: https://www.portsregulator.org/images/documents/Final_PR_ROD_201314.pdf [Accessed: 6 October 2018]


Ports Regulator of South Africa (2014b) Record of Decision – 28 March 2014 -Tariff Application by the National Ports Authority for the Tariff Year 2014/2015, available at: https://www.portsregulator.org/images/documents/Record-of-Tariff-Decision-2014-2015.pdf [Accessed: 6 October 2018]


Ports Regulator of South Africa (2015) Record of Decision – 2015/16 -Tariff Application by the National Ports Authority for the Tariff Year 2015/16-2017/18, available at: https://www.portsregulator.org/images/documents/Record-of-Decision-2015-16.pdf [Accessed: 6 October 2018]


Ports Regulator of South Africa (2016a) Record of Decision – 2016/17 -Tariff Application by the National Ports Authority for the Tariff Year 2016/17-2018/19, available at: https://www.portsregulator.org/images/documents/Record-of-Decision-2016-17.pdf [Accessed: 6 October 2018]


Ports Regulator of South Africa (2016b) Record of Decision 2017/18 - Tariff Application by the National Ports Authority for the Tariff Years 2017/18 - 2019/20, available at: https://www.portsregulator.org/images/documents/Ports-Regulator-Record-of-Decision-2017-18.pdf [Accessed: 6 October 2018]


Ports Regulator of South Africa (2017b) Record of Decision 2018/19 – Tariff Application by the National Ports Authority for the Tariff Years 2018/19 – 2020/21, available at: https://www.portsregulator.org/images/documents/NPA-Tariff-Record-of-Decision-1-December-2017.pdf [Accessed: 6 October 2018]


RSA, (2005). National Ports Act No. 12 of 2005. Government Gazette. Vol. 482 no. 27863. August 4, Cape Town, South Africa. Available at: http://www.info.gov.za/view/DownloadFileAction?id=67864 [Accessed: 6 October 2018]


RSA, (1962). Income Tax Act No.58 of 1962. Government Gazette. South Africa. Available at: http://www. gov.za/sites/default/files/gcis_document/201505/act-58-1962s.pdf [Accessed: 6 October 2018]


Santos, A. M. P., Mendes, J. P., and Guedes Soares, C. (2016). A dynamic model for marginal cost pricing of port infrastructures. Maritime Policy and Management, 43(7), 812-829, DOI: 10.1080/03088839.2016.1152404.


TNPA (2012), Transnet National Ports Authority. Position Paper on Tariff Methodology for the setting of Tariffs by Ports Regulator, available at: https://www.portsregulator.org/images/documents/Position_paper_on_Transnet_National_Ports_Authority_18_Sep.pdf [Accessed: 6 October 2018]


Transnet (2012), Transnet. Annual Financial Statements 2012, Available at: https://www.transnet.net/InvestorRelations/AR/2012Annual%20Financial%20Statements.pdf [Accessed: 6 October 2018]


Transnet (2013), Transnet. Annual Financial Statements 2013, Available at: https://www.transnet.net/InvestorRelations/AR/2013/Annual%20Financial%20Statements.pdf [Accessed: 6 October 2018]


Transnet (2014), Transnet. Annual Financial Statements 2014, Available at: https://www.transnet.net/InvestorRelations/AR/2014/Annual%20Financial%20Statements.pdf [Accessed: 6 October 2018]


Transnet (2015), Transnet. Annual Financial Statements 2015, Available at: https://www.transnet.net/InvestorRelations/AR2016/2016/downloads/FINAL_Transnet_AFS_2015_160715.pdf [Accessed: 6 October 2018]


Transnet (2016), Transnet. Annual Financial Statements 2016, Available at: https://www.transnet.net/InvestorRelations/AR2016/2016/1.%Transnet%20AFS%202016_consolidated%20financials_120616.pdf [Accessed: 6 October 2018]


Transnet (2017), Transnet. Annual Financial Statements 2017, Available at: https://www.transnet.net/InvestorRelations/AR2017/Transnet%20AFS%202017.pdf [Accessed: 6 October 2018]


Transnet (2018), Transnet. Annual Financial Statements 2018, Available at: https://www.transnet.net/InvestorRelations/AR2018/Transnet%20AFS_FINAL_310818.pdf [Accessed: 6 October 2018].

- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -



This report has been published by the Inclusive Society Institute

The Inclusive Society Institute (ISI) is an autonomous and independent institution that functions independently from any other entity. It is founded for the purpose of supporting and further deepening multi-party democracy. The ISI’s work is motivated by its desire to achieve non-racialism, non-sexism, social justice and cohesion, economic development and equality in South Africa, through a value system that embodies the social and national democratic principles associated with a developmental state. It recognises that a well-functioning democracy requires well-functioning political formations that are suitably equipped and capacitated. It further acknowledges that South Africa is inextricably linked to the ever transforming and interdependent global world, which necessitates international and multilateral cooperation. As such, the ISI also seeks to achieve its ideals at a global level through cooperation with like-minded parties and organs of civil society who share its basic values. In South Africa, ISI’s ideological positioning is aligned with that of the current ruling party and others in broader society with similar ideals.


Phone: +27 (0) 21 201 1589

Web: www.inclusivesociety.org.za

Comentarios


bottom of page